Show simple item record

dc.contributor.advisorMichael D. Whinston, Nikhil Agarwal and Amy Finkelstein.en_US
dc.contributor.authorOlssen, Alexander Lee.en_US
dc.contributor.otherMassachusetts Institute of Technology. Department of Economics.en_US
dc.date.accessioned2021-05-24T20:23:02Z
dc.date.available2021-05-24T20:23:02Z
dc.date.copyright2021en_US
dc.date.issued2021en_US
dc.identifier.urihttps://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/130758
dc.descriptionThesis: Ph. D., Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics, February, 2021en_US
dc.descriptionCataloged from the official PDF of thesis.en_US
dc.descriptionIncludes bibliographical references (pages 137-142).en_US
dc.description.abstractThis thesis comprises three essays on the industrial organization of health care markets. In the first essay, joint with Mert Demirer, I study how formulary-contingent rebates affect insurers formulary placement of branded statins. The prices charged for on-patent, branded pharmaceuticals represent a large, and controversial, component of medical spending in the U.S. In contrast to many countries and many other government programs, drug prices in the Medicare Part D program are determined by privately negotiated rebates between insurance plans and drug manufacturers. How large are these rebates? What would happen to formularies, consumer surplus, and firm profits if the government could increase the rebates of a blockbuster Medicare Part D drug? We estimate a simultaneous model of insurance demand and statin demand for the population of statin users in 2010. Our demand estimates allow us to quantify how insurer profits change under different statin formulary structures.en_US
dc.description.abstractWe use these profit functions to estimate the rebates for Crestor and Lipitor, two blockbuster drugs, using a moment inequality approach; we estimate rebates between 25% and 54% for branded statins. In counterfactuals, we analyze the effect of rebates on formulary design and consumer surplus. We show that increasing only Crestor rebates has no effect on consumer surplus because of offsetting effects on winners and losers. In contrast, increasing only Lipitor rebates does increase consumer surplus. If rebates reduced U.S. prices to match those paid in Canada, then consumer surplus would increase by up to 3.1% In the second essay, I compare estimates of formulary-contingent rebates using three empirical moment inequality models. Unobserved private rebates are an important determinant of the prices that insurers pay drug manufacturers in Medicare Part D. There is growing interest in understanding these negotiated rebates and there consequences on market equilibrium.en_US
dc.description.abstractHowever rebates are secret and have proven difficult to estimate. In this paper I compare three moment inequality models that I use to estimate formulary-contingent rebates for branded statins. The first model, which only allows for measurement error, imposes the strong assumption that their is no rebate heterogeneity that is unobserved to the econometrician. Due to the fact that different insurers use different agents (Pharmacy Benefit Mangers) in rebate negotiations, this assumption is unlikely to hold. As a consequence I develop two models that allow for unrestricted insurer-specific unobserved rebate heterogeneity. Somewhat surprisingly, the measurement errors only model produces reasonable results in this context, however the rebates for Lipitor are approximately twice as large in my preferred model relative to the measurement errors only model.en_US
dc.description.abstractIn the third essay, also joint with Mert Demirer, I study the effects of government negotiated drug prices using Nash-in-Nash bargaining models. One of the most controversial aspects of Medicare Part D is that the government is prohibited from being involved in price negotiations despite the fact that it provides almost $100 billion to the program in subsidies each year. We model pharmaceutical drug price setting using Nash-in-Nash bargaining models. We compare two models: one where insurers negotiate drug prices and another where the government negotiates prices. We show that the ability for the government to improve consumer surplus depends on both upstream and downstream market structure. With many insurers and few drug manufacturers, the government can increase consumer surplus, but with few insurers the government cannot increase consumer surplus no matter how much bargaining power it has vis-a-vis drug manufacturers.en_US
dc.description.abstractWe also show that a Nash-in-Nash bargaining model where insurers and drug manufacturers negotiate over both manufacturer prices and copays can be used to estimate unobservable manufacturer prices and bargaining weights as long as there are profit spillovers across bilateral negotiations.en_US
dc.description.statementofresponsibilityby Alexander Lee Olssen.en_US
dc.format.extent142 pagesen_US
dc.language.isoengen_US
dc.publisherMassachusetts Institute of Technologyen_US
dc.rightsMIT theses may be protected by copyright. Please reuse MIT thesis content according to the MIT Libraries Permissions Policy, which is available through the URL provided.en_US
dc.rights.urihttp://dspace.mit.edu/handle/1721.1/7582en_US
dc.subjectEconomics.en_US
dc.titleEssays on industrial organization and health care marketsen_US
dc.typeThesisen_US
dc.description.degreePh. D.en_US
dc.contributor.departmentMassachusetts Institute of Technology. Department of Economicsen_US
dc.identifier.oclc1252059319en_US
dc.description.collectionPh.D. Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economicsen_US
dspace.imported2021-05-24T20:23:02Zen_US
mit.thesis.degreeDoctoralen_US
mit.thesis.departmentEconen_US


Files in this item

Thumbnail

This item appears in the following Collection(s)

Show simple item record