Show simple item record

dc.contributor.authorAcemoglu, Daron
dc.contributor.authorGancia, Gino
dc.contributor.authorZilibotti, Fabrizio
dc.date.accessioned2013-02-06T01:50:05Z
dc.date.available2013-02-06T01:50:05Z
dc.date.issued2012-11-24
dc.identifier.urihttp://hdl.handle.net/1721.1/76741
dc.description.abstractTo study the short-run and long-run implications on wage inequality, we introduce directed technical change into a Ricardian model of offshoring. A unique final good is produced by combining a skilled and an unskilled product, each produced from a continuum of intermediates (tasks). Some of these tasks can be transferred from a skill-abundant West to a skill-scarce East. Profit maximization determines both the extent of offshoring and technological progress. Offshoring induces skill-biased technical change because it increases the relative price of skill intensive products and induces technical change favoring unskilled workers because it expands the market size for technologies complementing unskilled labor. In the empirically more relevant case, starting from low levels, an increase in offshoring opportunities triggers a transition with falling real wages for unskilled workers in the West, skill-biased technical change and rising skill premia worldwide. However, when the extent of offshoring becomes sufficiently large, further increases in offshoring induce technical change now biased in favor of unskilled labor because offshoring closes the gap between unskilled wages in the West and the East, thus limiting the power of the price effect fueling skill-biased technical change. The unequalizing impact of offshoring is thus greatest at the beginning. Transitional dynamics reveal that offshoring and technical change are substitutes in the short run but complements in the long run. Finally, though offshoring improves the welfare of workers in the East, it may benefit or harm unskilled workers in the West depending on elasticities and the equilibrium growth rate.en_US
dc.description.sponsorshipWe thank Lorenzo Caliendo, Arnaud Costinot, Gene Grossman, Esteban Rossi-Hansberg, Mathias Thoenig, Jonathan Vogel and seminar participants at many institutions and conferences for useful comments. Gino Gancia acknowledges financial support from the Barcelona GSE, the Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación (ECO2011- 25624) and the ERC Grant GOPG-240989. Fabrizio Zilibotti acknowledges financial support from the ERC Advanced Grant IPCDP 229883. MIT and CIFAR. Email: daron@mit.edu CREI, Barcelona GSE and CEPR. Email: ggancia@crei.cat. University of Zurich and CEPR. Email: fabrizio.zilibotti@econ.uzh.ch.en_US
dc.publisherCambridge, MA: Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technologyen_US
dc.relation.ispartofseriesWorking Paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Dept. of Economics;12-25
dc.rightsAn error occurred on the license name.en
dc.rights.uriAn error occurred getting the license - uri.en
dc.subjectDirected Technical Changeen_US
dc.subjectOffshoringen_US
dc.subjectSkill Premiumen_US
dc.subjectGrowth and Productivityen_US
dc.titleOffshoring and Directed Technical Changeen_US
dc.typeWorking Paperen_US


Files in this item

Thumbnail
Thumbnail

This item appears in the following Collection(s)

Show simple item record